Chat with us, powered by LiveChat W6D1 Wald | Gen Paper
+1(978)310-4246 credencewriters@gmail.com
  

SO
1,2

100

Strategic Outsourcing: An
International Journal
Vol. 1 No. 2, 2008
pp. 100-121
# Emerald Group Publishing Limited
1753-8297
DOI 10.1108/17538290810897138

Building strategic partnerships
for managing innovation

outsourcing
Peter Baloh

Faculty of Economics, University of Ljubljana, Ljubljana, Slovenia

Sanjeev Jha
University of Illinois at Chicago, Chicago, Illinois, USA, and

Yukika Awazu
Bentley College, Waltham, Massachusetts, USA

Abstract

Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to uncover the mechanisms of organizations managing
innovation outsourcing to business partners. In a business environment characterized by the
development of deep, niche expertise in a particular domain, business partnerships can provide a
source of innovative rejuvenation by outsourcing the innovation to business partners who have
complementary skills and expertise. This paper addresses a critical challenge which the
organizations are currently facing: how do you manage outsourcing of innovation to business
partners effectively while maintaining your strategic competitiveness?
Design/methodology/approach – Exploratory multiple case studies of over 30 innovative
European and US companies were done. It involved 50 semi-structured interviews with senior
executives from research and development, product management, information technology, and
marketing.
Findings – The paper identifies three complementary models of managing outsourcing of
innovation to business partner: acquisition, strategic alliances, and open source (OS). Based on these,
a three-dimensional ‘‘Co-Innovation Space’’ is proposed that can help in analysis and planning of
current and future innovation projects.
Research limitations/implications – Although the research is carefully designed, it is an
exploratory study and has the limitation of generalizability of the findings. Nevertheless, findings
from multiple case studies from diverse organizations shed a light to current innovation and strategic
alliance literature.
Practical implications – Partnerships can open the door to multiple knowledge sources. Accessing
and integrating information from these sources can greatly enhance knowledge base of organizations
and can help fuel sustainable innovation. The models proposed in this study provide a lens to
examine existing innovation project portfolios and/or to plan for future innovation programmes.
Originality/value – This study is probably among few to study such a large, diversified, and
geographically scattered group of organizations. Although exploratory and preliminary, this makes
the findings of the study insightful.

Keywords Innovation, Strategic alliances, Acquisitions and mergers, Partnership, Outsourcing

Paper type Conceptual paper

Introduction
Worldwide, executives agree that collaborative innovation is indispensable. When
asked about the most important sources of ideas and innovation, CEOs ranked
employees first (41 per cent of CEOs agree that they are the number one source), closely
followed by external sources such as business partners and customers (39 and 36
per cent, respectively (IBM, 2006)). Internal research and development (R&D)
departments, in contrast, ranked only eighth in importance (IBM, 2006). The nature of
innovation has undergone fundamental changes in recent times (Chesbrough, 2003).

The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at
www.emeraldinsight.com/1753-8297.htm

Building
strategic

partnerships

101

Today, it is not sufficient for an organization to simply rely on its internal knowledge
base for ideas (Carayannis, 1999; Chesbrough, 2003; Desouza et al., 2005; Dodgson,
1991; Hitt et al., 2000). Organizations have realized that they must partner with external
entities to source ideas, know-how, and capabilities.

Organizations have become highly specialized in niche areas, often focusing their
capabilities on specific expertise, services, or products. Organizations must hone in on
their core capabilities and engage with business partners to supplement, expand, and
apply knowledge. In this way, they can balance their deep expertise with partner’s
expertise in order to innovate efficiently and effectively; and this is what good
companies should do (Sull, 1999). While developing existing technology and serving
existing customers results in incremental innovations, exploration into new knowledge
or departure from existing skills leads to radical innovation serving emergent
customers or markets (March, 1991; Benner and Tushman, 2003; Herrmann et al., 2006).
Complementary assets help an organization extend the reach, scope, and impact of
their products and services to reach market faster with better and new products. This
realization has fuelled the recent surge of interest in outsourcing, both on- and off-
shore. Organizations engage in partnerships to reduce the costs of internal knowledge
creation. Moreover, when the need for knowledge in allied or foreign domains arises,
many organizations lack the capability or capacity to grow the knowledge in-house –
they need to negotiate for the ideas and know-how from external sources. Quinn (2000)
cites the example of large pharmaceutical companies outsourcing elements in their
innovation chain while specializing in their core activities. Breaking core competencies
into three broad areas of basic research, development, testing and production, and
distribution, the author argues that companies specialize in each of these three areas
while collaborating with other. Companies specializing in R&D build partnership with
firms having core competencies specializing in the other two elements in the
innovation chain: production (testing and production) and marketing, distribution, and
logistics (distribution).

Miozzo and Grimshaw (2005) argue that vertical disintegration and modularity of
innovation chain is one of the most significant phenomenons of modern organizations.
Organizations can generate faster and better products by breaking them into smaller
subsystems that can be built separately but to function together. However, to achieve
this, organizations need to have a sound strategy to manage the outsourcing of their
subsystems. We have examples of a number of organizations practicing outsourcing of
subsystems requiring their suppliers of components and services to conduct their own
innovations, while they focus on innovations in their core competency. Boeing actively
solicited business partners in the innovation process for its new 787 Jetliner (Kotha and
Nolan, 2005). Boeing created a team of 15 companies worldwide for production of the
structural sections of the plane. For example, Mitsubishi Heavy Industries (Japan) is
responsible for the wing box. Vogut and Alexia (Italy) are building the horizontal
stabilizer and the centre and aft fuselage. Product suppliers are not the only business
partners, either. Services can be outsourced, too. Most organizations today outsource
some aspect of their human resource functions (e.g. executive recruitment). In doing so,
they rely on the expertise of their providers to bring them the best-of-breed in both
product and service offerings.

The shift in the mindset towards outsourcing of innovation is driven by increased
competitive pressures. Globalization makes the need for innovating with business
partners more critical. In this age of rapid innovation, organizations cannot stay at a
static level of skills and competencies. Organizations need to ceaselessly create

SO
1,2

102

knowledge, innovate processes, and products, and learn from their predecessors’’
mistakes and services. Organizational improvisation (Cunha et al., 1999) is the mantra
to break out of this loop of the birth and death of organizations. The loop has always
been there, but globalization shortens the process. Organizations need to improvise,
experiment, and employ all their resources, especially their employees, business
partners, and customers, in a continual quest for organizational improvisation. This
demand and complexity helps to explain why opening an innovation process by
outsourcing external parties may be a challenging undertaking.

Further, innovating in isolation can be risky and costly. Out of ten R&D projects,
five flop, three are abandoned, and two go on to become successful (Rizova, 2006). A
large number of innovative ideas fail due to the lack of market orientation, such as with
misengineered products that do not fit customer needs. Consider the example of high-
definition television, a technology marvel that promised high picture quality. Philips,
Sony, and Thompson have invested millions and millions of dollars to produce consoles
since the early 1990s, but they were not in-sync with their business partners; the
product languished because the studio production equipment, signal compression
technologies, and broadcasting standards were not ready (Rizova, 2006). To maximize
profit potential, a company needs to identify its innovation fulcrum, the point at which
an additional offering destroys more value than it creates (Gottfredson and Aspinall,
2005).

If done properly, outsourcing to business partners can help organizations to achieve
sustained innovation and continuous competitive differentiation. Toyota is an excellent
example. Despite the amount of research conducted on the Toyota Production System
and the fact that Toyota even provides tours of its operations to other companies’
representatives, competitors have not been able to achieve the same level of
productivity as Toyota (Hagel and Brown, 2005). One important reason is that
knowledge resides and is owned at the network level. Participating suppliers benefit
from knowledge sharing as they themselves gain from others’ knowledge (Dyer and
Nobeoka, 2000).

In this paper, we describe three mechanisms by which organizations engage with
their business partners for outsourcing of innovation. These three modes of
collaboration are differentiated by the nature of relationships among partners, reasons
(goals) behind the decision for particular relationships, and by the scope of innovation.
In each business partnership, it is critical to identify what type of innovation is most
likely to result in successful outcomes. There is no one-size-fits-all approach.
Henderson and Clark (1990) classified innovations in two dimensions: one dimension
captures an innovation’s impact on components and the other on the linkages between
components. Through this classification, they identified multiple types of innovation:
incremental, modular, architectural, and radical innovation. Architectural innovation
illustrates how some business partnerships can lead to desired innovation effort
outcome. Henderson and Clark posit that architectural innovation is triggered by a
change in a component, which will create new interactions and new linkages in the
established product. Business partnerships often create this catalytic effect by
combining or incorporating complementary and necessary components in each
participant’s product and services. This type of innovation is very complex and risky,
and most often requires a variety of knowledge and expertise that are not located
internally in the firm. It can also be highly disruptive to organizations (Gatignon et al.,
2003). This paper focuses on such complex and disruptive innovation. We discuss
under what conditions each mechanism of outsourcing is beneficial, and the risks and

Building
strategic

partnerships

103

issues related with each mode of collaboration. We also explore the critical issues related
to actually introducing new forms of collaboration in organizations. Understanding
these issues can help organizations better manage the demanding and multifaceted task
of fusing business partners into already complex innovation processes. Finally, we
introduce a three-dimensional ‘‘Co-Innovation Space’’, which is akin to various matrices
(such as Boston Consulting Group (BCG), Arthur D Little (ADL), GE/McKinsey, etc.),
known from the strategic management. Companies can use it to analyze existing
innovation portfolios and/or to plan future approaches to innovation outsourcing.

The findings presented here are based on exploratory multiple case studies of over
30 innovative European and US companies. This research design was chosen as it suits
problems where the context of action is critical (Benbasat et al., 1987), as it enabled us
to gain a rich understanding of the context of the research (Saunders et al., 2003), and
as it made possible describing in greater detail the relationships that exist in reality in
local contexts (Galliers, 1992). Data collection involved 50 semi-structured interviews
with senior representatives from R&D, product management, information technology,
and marketing. The interview data were complemented by desk research, analysis of
corporate reports, and validated in follow-up sessions with key informants.

Building strategic partnerships for innovation outsourcing
During our exploratory study, three different forms of business partner collaboration
for innovation outsourcing emerged. In this section, they are defined and managerial
issues are discussed. The first collaborative mode is innovation through acquisition,
where ideas and innovations are acquired from another independent organization in
exchange for (usually monetary) compensation (Karim and Mitchell, 2004;
Lichtenthaler, 2005). The next type of collaboration is strategic alliances, where
numerous business partners engage in a highly dynamic interplay of tapping into
external sources of knowledge, assimilating new knowledge, and transforming and
exploiting the knowledge (Doz and Hamel, 1997; Hipkin and Naude, 2006). Finally, the
OS innovation model, which is where problems and ideas are exchanged via the
network to enable more rapid innovation and access to a wide array of sources of
expertise (Grand et al., 2004).

Outsourcing of innovation through external knowledge acquisition
Consider IBM, which realized US $1,700 million (20 per cent of their total net income) in
2000 via external commercialization of their expertise. This took the form of consulting
and services related to many of their 25,000 patents (IBM, 2005; Kline, 2003;
Lichtenthaler, 2005). The number of transactions involving the trading of knowledge
assets has increased significantly from US$ 15,000 million per year at the beginning of
the 1990s to around US$ 100,000 million a year in 2002 (Kline, 2003). If the supply side
is thriving, demand must be high. Many organizations engage in outsourcing of
innovation by purchasing knowledge from external entities.

Outsourcing of innovation through external acquisition has several benefits. First,
an organization can choose to purchase the best-of-breed and incur neither the cost nor
the risk of in-house innovation. Furthermore, in an era of specialized business, many
organizations focus upon specific areas of expertise, and their employees may not have
the diversity and breadth of knowledge to develop technological or product
innovations outside the business’s dominant field or business model.

Second, the purchasing organization can act in an agile manner and acquire
knowledge that arises out of emergent needs. When a need is recognized, a company

SO
1,2

104

can search for and buy the knowledge that will answer that need immediately. That
might take the form of new technology, manufacturing procedures, or a product
component. In these instances, an organization sidesteps the costly and sometimes
lengthy R&D cycle and is able to seize solutions found to match core competencies and
supplement organizational strengths. As the competitive environment is highly
dynamic, being able to satisfy emergent needs is critical.

Third, sometimes intellectual property safeguards particular pieces of knowledge.
In these instances, an organization may work with a business partner who has the
rights to a particular patent in order to use a specific product component or piece of
technology. The patent holder may retain the right to commercialize its knowledge
with other organizations; at other times, the patent itself will be for sale and can be
acquired entirely. Sometimes, a business partnership develops out of necessity to
access or utilize information held explicitly and legally by a partner. Consider the
example of Zebra Technologies. This leading manufacturer of industrial printing
solutions (such as bar code and radio-frequency identification (RFID) smart labelling)
has acquired an extensive portfolio of RFID-related patents in 2006. With a US$ 10
million acquisition of over 200 patents from UK-based medical company BTG plc,
Zebra now holds a vast collection of patents that secure their premium position in the
lucrative and promising area of products based around RFID technology. These
patents are integrated in their products, which are used by 90 per cent of the Fortune
500 companies. In addition, Zebra’s knowledge and expertise also is a viable consulting
industry with companies’ partners who try to stay in the supply chain. As an example,
in April 2006, Zebra held a conference for over 300 suppliers of Wal-Mart, who were
facing the giant retailer’s RFID compliance mandate.

The case of the ‘‘Little Swan’’ company (Pech et al., 2005) demonstrates that
innovation can be successfully integrated into a firm after direct acquisition.
Acquisition of foreign technology propelled the company from being a pottery and
domestic appliances producer with no history of technological development to a
company with an 18 per cent yearly expansion rate in the highly competitive and low-
profit-rate world market of white-ware manufacturing. Little Swan had the reputation
of being a ‘‘me-too’’ copycat rather than an innovator. In 1989, Little Swan was in 24th
place in washing machine sales in China and made a commitment to internal R&D
around that market. The transfer of critical technology and hiring of engineers from
the Japanese manufacturer Matsushita in 1987 acted as a catalyst, enabling Little Swan
to design proprietary technology of its own. The purchased expertise was paired with
incremental innovations from in-house R&D, which resulted in over 150 patents by the
year 2002, both in innovative products and in innovative manufacturing procedures.
Huge incentive programmes have been employed, and the company continuously
expands its knowledge base with experts from all over the world who can fruitfully
engage in new knowledge creation around diverse knowledge bases (Pech et al., 2005).

The case of South Korean electronics giant Samsung provides another an analogous
example. In the late 1990s, Samsung was associated with cheap TVs and microwaves
that flooded foreign markets. During the Asian economic crisis, Samsung undertook an
innovation transformation, starting first with improving acquired patents. While those
purchases improved products dramatically, they did not merely release as new
products. Instead, the acquisitions were paired with radical strategy shifts in
managerial training, strong leadership, and a huge R&D emphasis under the
watchword of quality. Today, Samsung is the third-ranked mobile phone producer in
the world; it was rated the ‘‘Mercedes’’ of cell phones (Manecksha, 2004) and has been

Building
strategic

partnerships

105

called ‘‘a killer innovator’’ (Ihlwan, 2006). For example, Samsung was the first to
introduce an MP3 player to the global market (two years before the iPod) and to
integrate MP3 players into mobile phones. It is the number two chip-maker in the
world after Intel and the top maker of LCD driver chips, with around 20 per cent of the
market; among its customers are Sony, Nokia, and Motorola.

The examples of Samsung and Little Swan emphasize that outsourcing of
innovation through acquisitions alone do not lead to sustainable innovation. In each of
these instances, key patents were acquired and then merged with new, high-quality
employees and a cultural shift towards valuing quality and innovation. The
combination of new knowledge and a cultural shift enabled both companies to develop
innovative products; the patents alone probably would not have had such a significant,
long-term impact. The process of integrating external knowledge opened the
organization up to new knowledge while simultaneously providing initial successes in
product development that further fuelled the process of change. This virtuous cycle
allowed Samsung and Little Swan to continually ramp up their innovation
programmes after each successful release of a product.

Critical considerations. Not all innovations are candidates for outsourcing through
external acquisitions. After both our literature review and our case studies, we put
forth the following hypotheses for future research. First, external acquisitions are
mainly suitable for products and services that have a rich history and a mature track
record. This is because such products and services are well understood, making it easy
to estimate their value and calculate their price. The prime example of this is in the
area of information technologies. Today, most organizations purchase their IT services,
solutions, and components from technology providers. Innovation in IT is not
conducted in-house. Rather, organizations have come to expect that the business
partners from whom they purchase these goods take responsibility for innovation.

Second, outsourcing through external acquisitions is ideal when the purchased
knowledge or ideas can be easily integrated into the current organizational fabric. By
this, we mean that the effort required to integrate innovations into the organization
should not be inordinately high enough to make it useless to purchase them off-the-
shelf. If there is need for special expertise to help the organization integrate these
innovations, the costs of the additional expertise need to be accounted for as part of the
overall project.

Third, outsourcing through external acquisitions should be used for purchasing
innovations in non-core areas of the organization. Non-core innovations, compared
with core innovations, are not critical to the operations of the business. Core
innovations can make or break a business; hence, when engaging with business
partners on core innovations it is better to use the second mechanism that we discuss,
innovation through strategic alliances.

Fourth, if a company feels that there is outstanding potential in particular
knowledge that can be bought, sometimes it engages in outsourcing knowledge
acquisition through transfer of patents from the commercializing to acquiring
company.

Outsourcing of innovation through strategic alliances
One of the main motivations for the creation of innovation-focused alliances is to
source new knowledge and learning. When two organizations are already
competitively strong, one or both parties may want to acquire critical knowledge, while
maintaining their own capabilities (Doz and Hamel, 1997; Kogut and Zander, 1992;

SO
1,2

106

Wonglimpiyarat, 2004). Alliances enable a company to intercept the technology of
another company and to close skill gaps faster than internal development would allow
(Doz and Hamel, 1997). Alliances also foster intense interaction and that collaboration
enables the transfer of tacit knowledge between members.

Strategic partners need to be sought out and a collaboration structure needs to be
formed. Relationships then need to be built and managed throughout the project
(Hipkin and Naude, 2006; Marshall, 2004). Doz and Hamel (1997) suggest that an
important antecedent for successful innovation alliances is the strategic,
organizational, and cultural compatibility of the partners. The selection and
engagement of complementary alliance members is critical for successful outsourcing
during innovation processes (Yoshingo and Rangan, 1995). The search for potential
partners must be systematic and consider contextual factors like competition, market
situation, and existing knowledge base. To facilitate the search, even web-based
evaluation tools have been devised (Humphreys et al., 2005). Strategic and cultural
issues come into play because the search for partners must also consider the roles that
the integrating company wants the partner to play in the alliance.

To find the appropriate partners for innovative alliances, several factors should be
considered. Achieving a strategic fit between the allies is vital (Rotering, 1990;
Teichert, 1994; Drejer, 2002; Lindman, 2002). Strategic fit (e.g. Rotering, 1990; Teichert,
1994) is related to the danger of opportunistic behaviour from one partner and therefore
inversely depends on the advantages both parties could gain out of the integration
(Dutta and Weiss, 1997). Appropriate partners need to be chosen considering the goals
set by the integrating company for a strategic alliance. In our study, interviewees
repeatedly stated that the complementary knowledge base of the business partner(s) is
the key selection factor. Trust and reliability is also important in selecting innovation
partners and is just as important as the complementary competences of both parties.
Unlike with external acquisitions, in strategic alliances both partners must have
knowledge to share and contribute and the benefits for both organizations must be
articulated and continually reinforced. Cultural fit is another critical consideration.
Cultural fit increases when decision processes and decision speed, tolerated risks, and
work-related values are similar. Also, the willingness to adapt to cultural differences,
which can arise both at an organizational and global level, improves the cultural fit.

Successful innovative alliances consider not only factors concerning the
organizations involved, but also the type of project being embarked upon. The results
of our study show that companies that are successful at integrating external
knowledge begin by considering the strategy for integration. They outline the goals of
the integration, roles for each company involved, and areas of integration. Our findings
principally support the findings of Wagner and Hoegl (2006), who studied the
integration of suppliers in the new product development process, and extend the data
to include technological (process) innovation. Companies distinguish between two
types of integration strategies – know-how and capacity projects.

In know-how projects, a firm’s intention is to utilize the specialized knowledge of a
business partner. For goal-oriented new product projects, which are highly innovative,
the integrating company takes on suppliers with deep knowledge in a particular area
and transfers the responsibility directly to the supplier (Wagner and Hoegl, 2006).
When embarking on strategic innovation alliances, it seems from the companies we
analyzed that such joint ventures have characteristics of the know-how projects. They
arise out of the need to adopt complementary knowledge when developing in-house

Building
strategic

partnerships

107

technological knowledge. Furthermore, not only the ‘‘end product’’, but also the ‘‘means
to that end product’’, is critical.

In that sense, we saw less transfer of responsibility to the strategic alliance partner
but more joint collaborative efforts in developing new ways of doing things. A recent
example is Samsung’s partnership with Mechanical Technology Inc. (MTI) Micro Fuel
Cells of Albany, NY (MTI), a unit of Mechanical Technology, a little-known company
that had $8 million in sales in 2005. MTI Micro has extensive technological knowledge
in the area of ‘‘green’’, micro-sized electricity sources. Samsung committed $1 million to
the joint development of fuel cells, one of the largest publicly disclosed commitments to
the technology by a major manufacturer in years. Goals, knowledge security, and the
question of intellectual property were explicitly defined in advance. The joint
development deal will last about 18 months, and neither company will work with any
other companies to develop fuel cells for use in wireless phones. Samsung secured an
exclusive license to use the technology from MTI Micro, and any patents that result
from the research will be assigned to MTI Micro.

Critical considerations. From the literature, we know that opportunities for
knowledge base expansion exist mainly in combining knowledge across new domains;
this recombination view of existing physical and conceptual resources has long been
accepted as a strong source of possible innovation (Schumpeter, 1934). However, while
outsourcing external knowledge from distant domains may be novel and valuable,
firms may have difficulties in absorbing and utilizing this knowledge. In line with this,
Hipkin and Naude (2006) agree that alliances will benefit mostly from multiple
capabilities, which may lead to haphazard, nonlinear outcomes. Specializing too much
in a particular domain, however, can lock a firm into a competency trap (Cohen and
Levinthal, 1990): ‘‘exploration in domains distant from a principal partner’s existing
competencies is likely to yield a more diverse set of innovations than when the
expertise of partners is closely linked’’ (Hipkin and Naude, 2006). However, the
absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Zahra and George, 2002) of companies
limits the assimilation of (too) distant knowledge, which will not be interpreted or
comprehensible, let alone combined with existing knowledge and acted upon (for
example, by launching a new product or improving existing technology).

An interesting word of advice to managers can be found in a study by Phene et al.
(2006), which deals both with strategic and cultural fit issues. As knowledge takes on
specific national characteristics due to various institutional factors, culture,
technological development, demand and supply conditions or scientific, technological,
and regulatory environments, the authors examined a geographical dimension –
together with an existing technological distance dimension – and its effects on chances
of breakthrough innovations. In view of strategic innovation alliances, members should
be chosen based on their geographic and technological context as follows (Phene et al.,
2006):

(1) Members with technologically distant knowledge should be coming from the
same national context; however, the effect is curvilinear, and therefore the
choice of external technologies should be made selectively and cautiously (e.g.
not too close and not too distant).

(2) When forging international alliances, breakthrough innovation is more likely to
occur when members with technologically proximate knowledge are chosen.

(3) Inviting members with technologically and geographically distant knowledge
simultaneously is unlikely to yield breakthrough innovation results, as due to

SO
1,2

108

distances on both dimensions, difficulties are likely to appear in the acquisition,
assimilation, transformation, and exploitation of knowledge.

Initially, a clear strategic direction based around existing knowledge of involved
partners is needed. Then, the alliance must shift towards the desired unknown, or the
unexplored direction, which entails the process of experimenting, discussing, and
transferring knowledge; thereby learning and changing both individuals and
organizations. These interactions result in unexpected idea development and problem
resolution, thus extending the knowledge base. Reaction to unanticipated
circumstances requires an emergent strategy (Mintzberg, 1978) in order to ‘‘take
advantage of unforeseen opportunities, or utilize radical technologies’’ (Hipkin and
Naude, 2006). Although the initial purpose of the alliance should guide action and
interaction, the relationship must be flexible enough to embrace unexpected knowledge
and technology.

It is crucial to recognize a dynamic nature of long-term relationships, in which it is
impossible to predict the result of collaboration and how innovation will affect long-
term goals. Also, imposing a static strategy in such dealings may delay or inhibit
technology advancements, as the strategy needs to adapt to and reflect newly gained
knowledge.

Knowledge-based alliances depend on the key players’ capabilities, and the
contribution of partners fluctuates as one partner’s expertise is superseded by that of
another. Lessons from a longitudinal case study involving a high-technology service
showed that the service was dependent on the behaviour and knowledge of partners,
who would create objectives on the fly; objectives would evolve through learning,
experimentation, and innovation, and a rigid and centrally led alliance targeting
innovation would only inhibit successful innovation (Hipkin and Naude, 2006).
Alliances should recognize the possibility of serendipitous outcomes and plan for such.
Consider Hipkin and Naude’s (2006) example of the South African lubrication division
of a UK-based multinational company. Because of deteriorating profit margins, they
entered an alliance to complement existing lubrication services with oil condition
monitoring. The original alliance model did not work – development was slow and
ambitions were limited. The principal partner expected other partners to be passive,
rather than instigators, of new ideas and was apprehensive about the destructive
power of new innovations. This strategy changed once principal partner recognized
the potential for added value that could be achieved through transferring skills and
knowledge between partners. Another partner, who had expertise in the field of
condition monitoring, assumed the leading role in the alliance and led the innovation
efforts. The principal partner allowed it (instead of blocking the initiative of the
‘‘smaller’’ partner, which often happens when principal partners fear loss of control in
the leadership role), supported the experimentation and free flow of information, and
finally, embedded the innovative technology into the added value service to their
customers all over the world.

These considerations suggest that outsourcing through knowledge-based alliances
require ‘‘loose–tight’’ governance, where partners are relatively autonomous in the
application and extension of their expertise, and where some sort of stable and defined
formal interaction is featured. In initial bursts of creativity and reactions to
possibilities, loose governance, with expertise leading the way, is more appropriate
than rigid structures of tight control, which may dampen creativity and innovation.
Early collaborative agreements should foster a learning culture to achieve strategic

Building
strategic

partnerships

109

agility, responsiveness to promoting fresh ideas, and the ability to pursue attractive
new opportunities and technologies (Yan and Gray, 1994). After the creativity of
partners and experimentation establishes a collaborative framework and areas of
focus, the direction of the alliance is more evident. Then a new strategic centre will
emerge and earlier loose governance can be replaced by a more steady-state set of
operations. Routines can then be standardized by all partners. At this point, more
direct control (tight governance structure) adds stability, but poses the danger of
blocking new market and technological ideas.

Outsourcing of innovation through the OS model
Most recently, OS software development has become a model of innovation through
external knowledge sources. It has developed from ‘‘garage’’ software products to
big-scale software developments. For instance, in 2005 Nokia launched
opensource.nokia.com, an internet portal for all of its OS software projects. Through
the portal, Nokia hopes to mobilize actual device users and business partners to further
innovate and customize the S60 software for their smart phones and the Maemo project
(a Linux-based internet tablet).

Most of the studies on the OS model have appeared in the software development
field, as this is where the OS movement originated (Grand et al., 2004). However, extant
findings can be applied to any area where knowledge becomes publicly available, as
our study shows. What makes this model interesting and unusual is the fact that the
OS developers employ their own resources and cover their own expenses to develop
innovative products or services, which are afterwards made publicly available for
adoption and adaptation by the end users or competitors. This challenges orthodox
economic theories, as it appears OS innovation does not require a return on investment
(from the individual perspective) and does not care about free riding (looking from
collective perspective). Why would a company choose to engage in OS-type
innovation? What drives a firm to allocate valuable resources to developing products
they then provide for free to users?

The answer is that OS players gain substantially increased innovation capabilities
and can derive financial benefits from drawing upon and contributing to commonly
held goods, services, and knowledge. OS innovation lies somewhere between the two
prevalent models of innovation (von Hippel and von Krogh, 2003; Ulhøi, 2004): the
private and the collective. In private innovation, results are developed and held
privately (Liebeskind, 1996), whereas in collective innovation firms work with public
institutions, and public access to results is enabled.

Grand et al. (2004) outlined a four level model of how a company can engage in an
open, innovative community. We have uncovered very similar characteristics in other
areas in which knowledge becomes publicly available. As an example (Table I), we
present two cases. One is a common OS example, a software development company.
The other is a consulting company that provides tactical and operationalizable advice
in the areas of process innovation, focusing on improvement of everyday working
practices, focused on knowledge management concepts, and deploying contemporary
IT tools.

Each level is concerned with certain costs and benefits, risks, and rewards. The
model inherently predicts that for undertaking any open software level, active
engagement is expected in the previous ones. As knowledge investments grow,
benefits accrue to the existing firm in terms of both increased knowledge and public
awareness and acclaim.

SO
1,2

110

Reputation and internal expertise are the main gains for OS-type companies. These are
built through augmentation of developed and released-to-public products as ideas are
amended and changed. Public release of knowledge includes a built-in process of
criticism and evaluation that allows developers to refine ideas, enhance their thinking
and understand diverse points of view.

For example, while Level 1 companies use only particular OS software (e.g. Apache
web server or OpenOffice personal productivity applications), a Level 2 company needs
to gain the knowledge and capability to adapt the piece of software to suit its particular
needs, as it offers the software as a complementary asset to its existing product (e.g.
Sony recently launched the Play Station 2 with a preinstalled Linux operating system,
which had to be extensively rewritten and adapted for the new platform). Furthermore,
at Level 3 a company chooses OS to be the design of its choice for particular projects
and actively joins the open development stream by giving out the source code. In this
way, the company taps into a global community of highly skilled people and is able to
acquire and assimilate outside knowledge, which is the most important benefit. At the
highest level, OS becomes the overall business model. At this point, companies are not
selling the IT artefact but rather, services around it. For instance, consider the case of
SUSE or the RedHat operating system: the companies realize their income by selling
CDs that help in the installation process.

In the OS-type consulting company in Table I, where a longitudinal study lasting
over eight years was undertaken (Grand et al., 2004), the use of the same four levels of
OS was evident over time. In the first stage, the company was established and the
founders had previously been employed in different companies, covering the business
areas of business process reengineering, organizational design, and project
management. They used publicly available knowledge such as textbooks, white
papers, practitioner and academic journals, to gain knowledge, which helped deliver
results in their everyday working practices. Level 2 started when the founders shifted
from their full-time jobs to consultants and transferred knowledge that they had and
that was available. With experience, employees gained the skills and willingness to
take on new knowledge acquisition. They started learning and creating original pieces
of research both on the academic and at the practitioner level. By publishing in local
business publications and appearing at business conferences with innovative

Table I.
Levels of engagement of
a company in open
community

Example 1: OS software development
company (Grand et al., 2004)

Example 2: OS-type consulting company (our
study)

Level 1: Only implements and uses OS
software

Level 1: Takes existing publicly available
publications (manuals, textbooks) and uses
them in everyday operations

Level 2: Adopts OS as a complementary
asset; adapts and extends it

Level 2: Takes existing publicly available
knowledge and uses it in the company’s
existing educational-consulting programmes

Level 3: Chooses OS software as the
design choice and commits substantial
resources to OS developers

Level 3: Employs researchers that create and
publish new knowledge and make it publicly
available. Employees gain expertise while
complementing their existing knowledge

Level 4: Becomes an OS core developer
and wraps the whole business model
with the OS paradigm

Level 4: Employees who create new knowledge
and make it publicly available sell their
knowledge and capabilities through consulting
services to other companies

Building
strategic

partnerships

111

presentations, the company also promoted itself and gained an image as ‘‘advanced
professionals’’ in the environment where they operated. As a final stage, employee
skills became an entry-point for high-end consulting projects, where innovative and
truly beneficial business operations improvements are necessary.

Open source companies make significant contributions to development and, at the
same time, extensively increase knowledge, development and innovation capabilities.
In effect, OS innovation requires a company to enter a period of continual
organizational and individual learning. With each iteration of publication, feedback
and modification, the core competencies are built upon, and expertise is both deepened
and extended. Extensive competencies can serve as a base for developing expert
services on OS software, which are sold mostly to Levels 1 and 2 companies. The full
potential of the OS community for knowledge creation and learning is realized in
Levels 3 and 4, as people engage in experiential learning while trying to exploit and
further explore expertise created by others. However, making that shift requires the
commitment of substantial resources as well as a deep understanding of the OS
business model and how it impacts and changes the innovation process.

The findings of Table I can be conceptualized and applied in other areas. For
example, universities, pharmaceutical companies, and other technologically driven
companies are also involved in publicly presenting their knowledge (for example,
academic publishing), thus, similar conclusions can be drawn in these arenas.

This model also seems to apply to the current changes in the music industry. With
the advent of easy-to-use and powerful personal computers, handhelds, and mobile
phones, digitization and file sharing are becoming ubiquitous. Record labels have been
struggling to retain the copyright laws in order to preserve their status and profit
margins, which lead to overpriced CD and DVD music. It seems that artists will have to
come up with a new business model; in a globally connected world where everyone can
download their music, they do not need the labels to stock millions of CD’s anymore.
Moreover, in the future, they might have to rely on harvesting the revenues solely from
performing live, while promoting their concerts with free or pay-if-you-like or pay-if-
you-earn-from-it types of access to their music. Songs themselves would thus only be a
promotion tool and a field where the artist learns, gains experience, and improves
capabilities.

A different manifestation of OS innovation has developed in scientific arenas.
Procter and Gamble (P&G) circulates science problems, throughout a network (Huston
and Sakkab, 2006), to address specific knowledge gaps. The sources of innovation in
the network are technology entrepreneurs around the world; suppliers; and open
networks (like YourEncore (retired scientists and engineers) and Yet2.com (an online
marketplace for intellectual property exchange)). The problem stories are presented to
these groups and anyone with an answer can respond. The traditional R&D
department may not have the answers, but among the myriad of scientists in the
network, someone does. P&G then integrates that knowledge into its specific problem
or context and continues to develop the product.

Similarly, Eli Lilly formed the subsidiary InnoCentive to create a business model of
external knowledge acquisition. The process is similar to bounty hunting in the Old
West: ‘‘Wanted’’ posters describing a scientific problem and a reward are posted, then
bounty hunters can compete in an online project room to answer first and best (Breen,
2002). Over 95,000 scientists from around the world now participate (Kramer, 2006).

A particular open innovation form is explored in Miles et al. (2005). The authors put
forth an idealized, futuristic example in the OpWin network, which was designed in

SO
1,2

112

accordance with the best business practices of today. The OpWin network is made up
of member companies, each of which are independent fiscal entities; a network services
hub that stores and disseminates information; and a management group that oversees
the process, states new objectives for the network and facilitates collaboration between
member firms. The OpWin network strives for continuous innovation, not just periodic
spikes of innovation.

Collaboration between OpWin members is aided by an enormous catalogue that
shares products, product improvements, innovations, market ideas, problems, and
solutions. Ongoing learning is led and facilitated by the management group, which
brings members together in functional teams (e.g. marketing) with trained facilitators
to help the group assist members in seeing new markets and strategies for those
markets. In order to enter the OpWin network, a member company must display
collaborative innovation. This is not a simple cooperation, where joint aims are met
with clear goals; members must display the hallmarks of adaptability and knowledge
transfer across companies.

How does this differ from collaboration today? Miles et al. (2005) emphasize that all
ideas and processes of member firms are open to the network. All members can use
ideas or processes generated by any member of the network, and must acknowledge
the source of their knowledge. Even in cases of disagreement, different worldviews or
other friction, some have argued that innovation emerges at the areas of conflict
because that is precisely where key issues are revealed (Hagel and Brown, 2005).

Critical considerations. A company needs to decide on the business model and
allocation of resources when choosing to engage in the OS environment, as only then
can appropriate management interventions can be applied. Our findings suggest that
two business models are prevalent in OS innovation-type companies. The first is
geared towards the new market creation. For example, while publishing white papers
and thus freely distributing knowledge, a consulting company gains an ‘‘expert’’ image,
suggesting to clients that this particular company can solve particular type of complex
business problems. The company thus creates the need for their knowledge. At the
same time, that knowledge is available through value-added solutions such as
consultancy, IT implementations, etc. The second OS business model is dual licensing
of a product or service. Here, for instance, a consulting company publicly publishes
and freely distributes a summary of a market report. If the reader wants more detail, a
complete report is available for a fee.

Open source innovation is a highly specific but open partnership requiring careful
consideration before implementation in a particular business context. Three specific
characteristics of OS development, pertinent to knowledge creation beyond firm
boundaries, can be outlined from our findings.

First, OS development represents a unique combination of public and privately held
knowledge. The artefact itself is publicly available while expertise is held privately
with developers. OS players gain substantially in increased innovation capabilities and
can derive financial benefits from drawing upon and contributing to a commonly held
good. This model is particularly appropriate when an organization can identify
modules of knowledge. Modularity is part of why software development thrives in an
OS environment; different sources can easily be integrated, and components can be
developed externally or internally and then integrated. Procter & Gamble and
InnoCentive’s approaches both emphasize modularity rather than process. By seeking
specific answers and specific types of knowledge, OS can be directed and strategically

Building
strategic

partnerships

113

embarked upon. In industries or knowledge domains where segmentation of knowledge
can be undertaken easily, OS innovation becomes much easier to manage and direct.

This modularity is not the only approach to OS innovation. The OS software
movement is overcoming this approach by considering and deriving competitive
advantage from the community aspects of OS. This second consideration of using OS
innovation requires engagement with an OS community is a highly dynamic exchange
process, as the community often presents an instant review of the knowledge released.
With the OS ‘‘2.0’’ concept (as noted in Fitzgerald, 2006), not only horizontal
infrastructure is being developed sporadically by a group of relatively ad hoc developer
group. Rather, OS software developers start with a purposive strategy to gain
competitive advantage (over proprietary SW developers) by building purposive vertical
information system (IS) solutions in a less bazaar-like managed manner (Fitzgerald,
2006). With the latter, in-depth overall requirements analysis is not needed as the
software users are also developers, who indulge in improving particular modules on an
individual basis. There is no need for reconciliation of viewpoints because development
tasks improve a known software design in a modular manner. When more developers are
working jointly on an innovative software product, analysis and design becomes more
complex in vertical sense as pieces of code are highly dependent or even impossible to be
divided in modules and coupled back at the end. Developers need to act as a part of a
highly orchestrated joint effort.

Fitzgerald (2006) notes that the ‘‘mythical characterization’’ of OS software as a
collective of ‘‘supremely talented hackers’’ freely volunteering their knowledge towards
development of software that stands up against existing proprietary solutions (c.f.
Ljungberg, 2000), is an outdated one. Indeed, ‘‘the haphazard principle of individual
developers perceiving ‘‘an itch worth scratching’’ is superseded by corporate firms
considering how best to gain competitive advantage from open source’’ (Fitzgerald,
2006). Evidence from our case of a consulting company conforms to the latter, as
adoption of the OS model in the company is deliberate, with the company’s strategy
being built strictly around the OS principles. It is of crucial importance to recognize the
difference between codified knowledge (in a form of artefacts such as pieces of code or
journal articles) and the tacit knowledge inherent in cumulative experience, collective
working practices, and organizational routines. Only these can act as a true source of
competitive advantage in the OS model. Any organization must carefully consider
what knowledge should be public and what private expertise backs that knowledge up
in order to understand and increase their competitive advantage.

Third, co-creation of the public good is beyond any team, organizational, or other
boundaries. As opposed to traditional business models, ‘‘competing’’ innovators benefit
from their cooperation, as their competences grow with each project. From the
perspective of the collective, publicly available knowledge grows too and pushes the
frontiers of knowledge domains further. ‘‘The value of knowledge increases with wide
consumption’’ (Ulhøi, 2004), which marks a fundamental difference in economic
approach and the possibility for competitive advantage.

When considering OS-type innovation with external partners, companies need clear
answers to two questions. First, whether free riders, having access to the ‘‘open’’
product, can benefit substantially (and relatively more as true innovators) from gaining
reputation or competences. If they do, the OS business model is not appropriate.
Second, does making knowledge publicly available, improve possibilities of the
innovator to capitalize upon competences gained, increased reputation, and/or new
product/market created?

SO
1,2

114

Discussion
To help organizations better manage their innovation agendas, we proposed three
models of outsourcing of innovation through business partner: innovation through
acquisition, innovation through strategic alliances, and OS innovation. These models
emerged through our exploratory study of over 30 US and European companies that
had a track record of successfully innovating with external partners. Due to
exploratory nature of the research, a pragmatic selection of case studies has been
made. Additional empirical research will help reveal deeper insights into the
organizational design of the integration process based on key layout elements and
parameters. The findings presented are based on limited number of organizations. We
acknowledge and understand the issue of generalizability, and have taken necessary
steps when designing our research. To generalize our findings, future research needs to
be done. We view our study as exploratory and preliminary, yet insightful. We wish to
lay the foundation for future enquiry and therefore to contribute to the highly relevant
research stream of showing the role and potential of enabling and supporting
demanding open and distributed organizational processes.

Outsourcing of innovation through external knowledge acquisition is beneficial when
expertise exists outside, which can be purchased easily, swiftly, and immediately put to
use by integration into the organizational fabric. In these cases, organizations may not
choose to invest resources in innovating from scratch. In addition, since these pieces of
knowledge are exclusive properties of partners, competitive advantage can be gained
through knowledge acquisition. However, not every required piece of knowledge is
available in the market. Most of the time external acquisition of knowledge is available
for only mature products with rich history. For example, organizations may purchase
new IT services rather than innovating themselves if they do not have the requisite IT
expertise. Further, acquisition of knowledge should be done for the non-core areas of the
business. Core innovations provide competitive advantage, profitability, and growth and
hence organizations need to be actively engaged in innovations in core areas, while
judiciously obtaining innovations in non-core areas from the market.

Outsourcing of innovation through strategic alliances has become a popular
mechanism of innovation, given the increased level of competition with globalization
and the need for rapid innovation. Organizations cannot rely solely on their internal
skills and competencies; they need to actively work with business partners to harness
partners’ knowledge and recombine with their own to bring out new products and
services. Unlike the case of direct knowledge acquisition, in the case of innovation
through strategic alliances, the end result is not always clear. However, the modalities
of cooperation, areas of integration, and roles of each partner are well defined. Apart
from benefiting from each others’ knowledge, organizations also share the risks of
innovation by pooling resources and expertise. However, since the engagement
requires a long-term view and commitment when compared with acquisition, the risk
of a mismatch between partners is always present. Hence, for successful innovation
alliances, organizational, cultural and strategic compatibility is critical. Organizations,
therefore, need to hone the skills of finding strategic partners and understanding the
contextual factors like competition, market situation, and existing knowledge base.
Even after finding the right partner, establishing the right kind of governance for the
alliance is equally important. Knowledge-based alliances require a ‘‘loose–tight’’
governance mechanism to ensure adequate autonomy and control.

Compared to outsourcing of innovation through knowledge acquisition and
strategic alliances, outsourcing innovation through OS model is a new phenomenon.

Building
strategic

partnerships

115

Although, most of the OS innovation has happened in software development field, the
concept is equally applicable in any area where experts are outside the organization.
The central concept is gaining knowledge from a community. However, organizations
need to have a proper business model in place to develop a successful OS innovation
model. Despite the simplicity of the model, organizations need to carefully plan OS
innovation model in the context of a business problem, because of the issue of engaging
people in sharing their privately held knowledge. It is also important to appreciate the
difficulty of appropriating tacit knowledge from people and organizations need to be
ready with circumventing this issue. Further, it is critical to be aware of the issue of
competitors gaining access to the knowledge and being part of the community. OS is a
potent mechanism of innovation, but organizations good business plans for success.

Our assumption that business partnerships are dynamic relationships suggested
that the success of innovation depends on correctly matching the type of business
partner innovation to an organization’s current abilities and organization’s strategy for
the future. Table II summarizes considerations for matching that have been recognized
as crucial in each of the business partner innovation models.

Table II illustrates that matching the type of business partner innovation to an
organization’s current abilities can greatly assist in success. For instance, for
organizations with a strong learning culture and a sustained base of long-term
employees innovating consistently, OS innovation can exponentially increase
knowledge and lead to highly successful consulting services.

Table II also indicates that organizations need to make conscious strategic choices that
will fit best their innovation projects. Observations from our exploratory study indicate
that the three models of business partner innovation are used in a portfolio manner.
Mature organizations with sustainable innovation programmes seem to be comfortable
and agile with each of the business partner innovation models, which are called upon as
needed to meet the needs of the innovation projects. It seems they use them at the same
time within different projects – both in a straightforward or (any other) hybrid form.

The three mechanisms of innovation outsourcing can be represented as a three-
dimensional space where companies manoeuvre to seek, manage, and achieve their
innovation. The three axes of this space are the scope of the innovation (the resources
necessary to carry it out), the impact upon existing business strategy (comparative
strength and position competitively), and the need for customization (functional
changes). The degree of customization required is the amount of effort and need to
tailor a particular innovation or the existing structures of an organization for effective
use of that innovation in a competitive context. The scope of the innovation is a way of
evaluating the likely impacts on the organization and its target consumers. The effect
on existing business strategy is a crucial factor, because innovations that have
substantial effects on business strategy will require careful communication and likely
will not be able to be acquired, as discussed above. These three factors tend to rise and
fall together. A project with a large scope often requires high customization and many
changes in business strategy. The three types of business partner innovation discussed
in this paper are also most suited for different levels of these factors. Acquiring
innovations has been discussed as most suitable for low customization, low scope of
innovation, and low impact on business strategy. On the other hand, business partner
alliances are best for mid-range projects that have some customization, a medium
scope and a not insignificant impact on business strategy. OS innovation tends to
require high customization, a broad scope, and significant business strategy changes.
Each type of innovation has different degrees of variance related to Table II. The

SO
1,2

116

Table II.
Characteristics of
business partner
innovation models

Characteristic
Innovation through
knowledge acquisition

Innovation through
strategic alliances

Open source
innovation model

Nature of
relationship with
business partner

Acquire business
partner’s privately held
knowledge

Collaborative
innovation efforts.
Relationship can be
characterized as
‘‘partnership’’ or
‘‘buyer–supplier’’,
depending on
the type of
alliance

Four levels of
integration relations,
from strict
supplier–buyer to
alliance-type of
relationship

Reason behind the
decision for
particular
relationship

Purchase already
‘‘proven-in-practice’’
knowledge, adopt it
and utilize it

Know-how projects:
transfer of tacit
technological
knowledge,
complementing an
existing knowledge
base Capacity
projects: bridge the
lack of internal
R&D resources for
less critical projects

Depends on level of
involvement. From
capitalizing
internally upon
existing, publicly
available knowledge
up to deliberate
creation of new
public knowledge
with goal to build
competences in
form of tacit
knowledge,
cumulated
experience and
collective working
practices that are
used to deliver
products

Scope of innovation Essentially less
innovative; however,
some companies, after
adopting the acquired
knowledge, advanced it.
With that, they built
innovation capability,
and started innovating
on their own

Know-how projects:
process innovation
changes the way a
company does
things, business
processes, and
technology,
resulting in
potentially very
different
(innovative)
products Capacity
projects: less
innovative,
incremental
product
changes

From none to
technological
(process) innovation
– depending on the
level of OS
involvement

Example Patents (e.g. IBM’s
patents base)

Joint collaboration
efforts, e.g. high-
definition television

OS software (e.g.
Linux), consulting
companies offering
‘‘free’’ academic
texts and
research results
to the public

Building
strategic

partnerships

117

strategic goals that lead to an organization’s choosing a particular innovation strategy
can be represented along the axes, from specific, off-the-shelf product integration to
business strategy innovations. There can be some degree of variance on each axis, and
we can use this variance to locate companies’ practice in the space and then explain
how successful companies strategically choose when and how to move from one spot to
another. This approach is akin to various matrices (such as BCG, ADL, GE/McKinsey,
etc.), known from the strategic management discipline.

One example of use of such three-dimensional ‘‘Co-innovation space’’ is shown in
Figure 1, where an organization’s portfolio of innovation projects could be sketched.

Using the conceptual space represented in Figure 1, a company can analyze its
existing innovation portfolio. This awareness can increase their competitiveness with the
innovation projects. The questions that should arise in such analysis are the following:

(1) What types of innovation are our current innovation projects?

(2) What kind of innovation projects do we want in the future? An appropriate
portfolio of approaches should reflect both the current abilities and strategic plans
for the future, as we have seen that three business-partner-innovation-approaches
are to be used in different organizational and business environment settings.

(3) Moreover, by scaling the representation of projects in this figure, organizations
can answer this question: how much commitment (e.g. in terms of financial or
human resources) do our innovation projects take? Not all the innovation projects
are equally important and thus do not involve equal amount of resource
commitment.

Consider another example. Using this three-dimensional space, organizations can
analyze and discuss ‘‘where it stands today’’, ‘‘where it will stand tomorrow’’, and
‘‘where it wishes to stand in the future’’. Namely, it could be argued that companies may
take one overall innovation approach over the other two for a moment. Then, they
move from one approach to another as market (or other) conditions allow/force them to

Figure 1.
Co-innovation space

SO
1,2

118

do so. While doing that, appropriate decisions regarding future innovation orientation
need to be made. According to their strategic roadmap, organizations can visualize
their goals and approaches for business partner innovation.

Such a graphical representation can have tremendous implication in terms of
research also. Consider the aspect of degree of commitment. It could be argued that not
all the firms with innovation strategy go with equal amount of commitment or
resources. The issues that remain to be answered by further research are:

(1) Are all the organization the same in their commitment or scale with that
innovation option (i.e. strategic alliance)? Do they have only one alliance or
many? Is the alliance critical for their future? Is the alliance a long-term option?

(2) If companies differ in their commitment or strategic alliances give different
values to the partner companies, why do the companies differ?

Future research should explore the situational factors under which companies choose
to use a particular model. Perhaps firm size, market position, and other things shape
the understanding of how organizations choose their position in that particular
innovation strategy. The situational factors that could be considered include the
market environment, the competitive situation, the product specificity, the level of
technologies, partner characteristics, and the company’s in-house innovation culture to
test the impact and success of these three models of innovation. The same argument
can be applied to the other two axes as well. It would be also interesting to answer
whether companies in a certain position in three-dimensional space can survive the
market competition with their current innovation approach.

Each concentric circle represents a different approach to business partner innovation.
Projects with the smallest scope, least customization, and smallest impact on business
strategy are best suited to be acquisition type projects. On the other hand, in projects
where customization is known to be high, the scope of the innovation is very high and
the eventual impact on business strategy is expected to be high, OS-type innovation is
more suited. Business partner alliances typically fall in the middle for all factors.

This is not to say that innovation is wholly an organization-wide endeavour. Figure 1
seeks to explore the strategic needs of business partner innovation, but organizations
must also remember to balance knowledge needs. Rapid innovations make developing
both specialized and broad technological knowledge bases extremely difficult.
Complementary competencies and specialized knowledge are needed in all innovation
efforts to give the edge to an innovation. In particular, organizations need to hunt for and
retain motivated and talented individuals and teams to help them generate innovations.
Organizations must create an environment of creativity and trust in which individuals
can see their dreams to fruition.

Conclusion
Partnerships open the door to multiple knowledge sources, such as internal R&D
activities, research conducted by partner organizations, and scientific knowledge
available through public innovation. Accessing and integrating information from these
sources can greatly enhance the knowledge base of a single organization and feed into
a cycle of sustainable innovation. Strong, well-matched business partners can form the
backbone of a virtuous cycle of increasing innovation. Collaboration, paired with
differing worldviews and clear objectives, can result from business partner innovation
processes when risks are managed and success factors well considered.

Building
strategic

partnerships

119

References

Benbasat, I., Goldstein, D.K. and Mead, M. (1987), ‘‘The case research strategy in studies of
information systems’’, MIS Quarterly, Vol. 11, p. 368.

Benner, M.J. and Tushman, M.L. (2003), ‘‘Exploitation, exploration, and process management: the
productivity dilemma revisited’’, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 28, pp. 238-56.

Breen, B. (2002), ‘‘Lilly’s R&D prescription’’, Fast Company, Issue 57, April ed., Mansueto
Ventures LLC, New York, NY.

Carayannis, E.G. (1999), ‘‘Knowledge transfer through technological hyperlearning in five
industries’’, Technovation, Vol. 19, pp. 141-61.

Chesbrough, H.W. (2003), Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Creating and Profiting from
Technology, Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.

Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990), ‘‘Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and
innovation’’, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 35, pp. 128-53.

Cunha, M.P., Cunha, J.V. and Kamoche, K. (1999), ‘‘Organizational improvisation: what, when,
how, and why’’, International Journal of Management Review, Vol. 1, pp. 299-341.

Desouza, K.C., Awazu, Y. and Jasimuddin, S. (2005), ‘‘Utilizing external sources of knowledge’’,
KM Review, Vol. 8, pp. 16-19.

Dodgson, M. (1991), The Management of Technological Learning: Lessons from a Biotechnology
Company, Walter de Gruyter, Berlin, New York, NY.

Doz, Y. and Hamel, G. (1997), ‘‘The use of alliances in implementing technology strategies’’,
in Tushman, M.L. and Anderson, P. (Eds), Managing Strategic Innovation and Change,
Oxford University Press, New York, NY.

Drejer, A. (2002), ‘‘Situations for innovation management: towards a contingency model’’,
European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 5, pp. 4-17.

Dutta, S. and Weiss, A.M. (1997), ‘‘The relationship between a firm’s level of technological
innovativeness and its pattern of partnership agreements’’, Management Science, Vol. 43,
pp. 343-56.

Dyer, J.H. and Nobeoka, K. (2000), ‘‘Creating and managing a high-performance knowledge-
sharing network: the Toyota case’’, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 21, pp. 345-67.

Fitzgerald, B. (2006), ‘‘The transformation of open source software’’, MIS Quarterly, Vol. 30,
pp. 587-98.

Galliers, R.D. (1992), ‘‘Choosing appropriate information systems research approaches’’,
in Galliers, R.D. (Ed.), Information Systems Research: Issues, Methods and Practical
Guidelines, Blackwell Scientific Publications, Oxford.

Gatignon, H., Tushman, M.L., Smith, W. and Anderson, P. (2003), ‘‘A structural approach to
assessing innovation: construct development of innovation locus, type, and
characteristics’’, Management Science, Vol. 48, pp. 1103-22.

Gottfredson, M. and Aspinall, K. (2005), ‘‘Innovation versus complexity: what is too much of a
good thing?’’, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 83, pp. 62-71.

Grand, S., Von Krogh, G., Leonard, D. and Swap, W. (2004), ‘‘Resource allocation beyond firm
boundaries: a multi-level model for open source innovation’’, Long Range Planning, Vol. 37,
pp. 591-610.

Hagel, J. and Brown, J.S. (2005), ‘‘Productive: how difficult business partnerships can accelerate
innovation’’, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 83, pp. 82-91.

Henderson, R.M. and Clark, K.B. (1990), ‘‘Architectural innovation: the reconfiguration of existing
product technologies and the failure of established firms’’, Administrative Science
Quarterly, Vol. 35, pp. 9-30.

SO
1,2

120

Herrmann, A., Tomczak, T. and Befurt, R. (2006), ‘‘Determinants of radical product innovations’’,
European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 9, pp. 20-43.

Hipkin, I. and Naude, P. (2006), ‘‘Developing effective alliance partnerships: lessons from a case
study’’, Long Range Planning, Vol. 39, pp. 51-69.

Hitt, M.A., Ireland, R.D. and Lee, H. (2000), ‘‘Technological learning, knowledge management,
firm growth and performance: an introductory essay’’, Journal of Engineering and
Technology Management, Vol. 17, pp. 231-46.

Humphreys, P., Huang, G. and Cadden, T. (2005), ‘‘A web-based supplier evaluation tool for the
product development process’’, Industrial Management & Data Systems, Vol. 105, pp. 147-63.

Huston, L. and Sakkab, N. (2006), ‘‘Connect and develop: inside Proctor & Gamble’s new model
for innovation’’, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 84, p. 58.

IBM (2005), Patents Portfolio, IBM, available at www.ibm.com/ibm/licensing/patents/portfolio.
shtml (accessed 12 July 2006).

IBM (2006), ‘‘CEO global study’’, IBM, available at www-03.ibm.com/press/us/en/attachment/
19289.wss?field¼ATTACH_FILE1 (accessed 15 March 2006).

Ihlwan, M. (2006), ‘‘Samsung’s high design, lower profit cell phone strategy’’, Business Week
Online, 14 July.

Karim, S. and Mitchell, W. (2004), ‘‘Innovating through acquisition and internal development:
a quarter-century of boundary evolution at Johnson & Johnson’’, Long Range Planning,
Vol. 37, pp. 525-47.

Kline, D. (2003), ‘‘Sharing the corporate crown jewels’’, MIT Sloan Management Review, Vol. 44,
pp. 89-93.

Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1992), ‘‘Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the
replication of technology’’, Organization Science: A Journal of the Institute of Management
Sciences, Vol. 3, pp. 383-97.

Kotha, S. and Nolan, R. (2005), ‘‘Boeing 787: the dreamliner’’, Harvard Business School Case Study,
9-305-101.

Kramer, H. (2006), ‘‘Brainy website takes advances to market’’, New York Post, NYP Holdings Inc.,
New York, NY.

Lichtenthaler, U. (2005), ‘‘External commercialization of knowledge: review and research
agenda’’, International Journal of Management Reviews, Vol. 7, pp. 231-55.

Liebeskind, J.P. (1996), ‘‘Knowledge, strategy, and the theory of the firm’’, Strategic Management
Journal, Vol.17, pp. 93-107.

Lindman, M.T. (2002), ‘‘Open or closed strategy in developing new products? A case study of
industrial NPD in SMEs’’, European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 5, pp. 224-36.

Ljungberg, J. (2000), ‘‘Open source movements as a model for organising’’, European Journal of
Information Systems, Vol. 9, pp. 208-16.

Manecksha, F. (2004), ‘‘Samsung plans more new mobile phones’’, New Straits Times, NST online,
Kuala Lumpur.

March, J.G. (1991), ‘‘Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning’’, Organization
Science, Vol. 2, pp. 71-87.

Marshall, C. (2004), ‘‘The dynamic nature of innovation partnering: a longitudinal study of
collaborative interorganizational’’, European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 7,
pp. 128-40.

Miles, R.E., Miles, G. and Snow, C.C. (2005), Collaborative Entrepreneurship: How Communities of
Networked Firms Use Continuous Innovation to Create Economic Wealth, Stanford
Business Books, Palo Alto, CA.

Mintzberg, H. (1978), ‘‘Patterns in strategy formation’’, Management Science, Vol. 24, pp. 934-48.

Building
strategic

partnerships

121

Miozzo, M. and Grimshaw, D. (2005), ‘‘Modularity and innovation in knowledge-intensive business
services: IToutsourcing in Germany and the UK’’, Research Policy, Vol. 34, pp. 1419-39.

Pech, R.M., Pech, R.J., Wei, D. and Shi, H. (2005), ‘‘Innovation through acquisition: the Jiangsu
Little Swan Group Company in the People’s Republic of China’’, European Journal of
Innovation Management, Vol. 8, pp. 107-19.

Phene, A., Fladmoe-Lindquist, K. and Marsh, L. (2006), ‘‘Breakthrough innovations in the US
biotechnology industry: the effects of technological space and geographic origin’’,
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 27, pp. 369-88.

Quinn, J.B. (2000), ‘‘Outsourcing innovation: the new engine of growth’’, Sloan Management
Review, Vol. 41, pp. 13-28.

Rizova, P. (2006), ‘‘Are you networked for successful innovation?’’, MIT Sloan Management
Review, Vol. 47, p. 49.

Rotering, C. (1990), Forschungs-und Entwicklungskooperationen zwischen Unternehmen. Eine
empirische Analyse, Schäffer-Poeschel, Stuttgart.

Saunders, M., Lewis, P. and Thornhill, A. (2003), Research Methods for Business Students,
Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Schumpeter, J.A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital,
Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle, Harvard U.P., Cambridge, MA.

Sull, D.N. (1999), ‘‘Why good companies go bad’’, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 77, pp. 42-52.

Teichert, T. (1994), Erfolgspotential internationaler F&E-Kooperationen, DUV, Wiesbaden.

Ulhøi, J.P. (2004), ‘‘Open source development: a hybrid in innovation and management theory’’,
Management Decision, Vol. 42, pp. 1095-114.

Von Hippel, E. and Von Krogh, G. (2003), ‘‘Open source software and the ‘Private-Collective’
innovation model: issues for organization science’’, Organization Science: A Journal of the
Institute of Management Sciences, Vol. 14, p. 209.

Wagner, S.M. and Hoegl, M. (2006), ‘‘Involving suppliers in product development: insights from
R&D directors and project managers’’, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 35, pp. 936-43.

Wonglimpiyarat, J. (2004), ‘‘The use of strategies in managing technological innovation’’,
European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 7, pp. 229-50.

Yan, A. and Gray, B. (1994), ‘‘Bargaining power, management control, and performance in United
States–China joint ventures: a comparative case study’’, The Academy of Management
Journal, Vol. 37, pp. 1478-517.

Yoshingo, M. and Rangan, U. (1995), Strategic Alliances: An Entrepreneurial Approach to
Globalization, Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.

Zahra, S.A. and George, G. (2002), ‘‘Absorptive capacity: a review, reconceptualization, and
extension’’, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 27, pp. 185-203.

Corresponding author
Peter Baloh can be contacted at: [email protected]

To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: [email protected]
Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

error: Content is protected !!